London
"When using climate models to calculate optimal greenhouse gas emission scenarios, there are two common approaches: cost-benefit analysis and cost-effectiveness analysis. Cost-benefit analysis minimises the cost of emission reductions and the anticipated costs of damage caused by climate change over the coming centuries; at the same time, the model maximises human welfare. Cost-effectiveness analysis minimises only the cost of emission reductions but adds a constraint: to stay below a given temperature target, such as 1.5 or 2°C. Alternatively, instead of a temperature constraint, the models can use a constraint on the atmospheric CO2 concentration or cumulative emissions. Constraints are often applied only after the year 2100, allowing the model to ‘overshoot' the target before 2100. For the same temperature outcome in 2100, emissions reductions in cost-effectiveness models tend to happen later than in cost-benefit analysis. This paper evaluates the welfare cost of this delay, using several types of cost-effectiveness constraints and comparing results from cost-benefit and cost-effectiveness models.
In their (welfare-maximising) benchmark cost-benefit model, the authors find that a 1.5°C target in 2100 requires very rapid emission reduction in the coming decades. There are almost no net negative emissions at the end of the century (i.e. relying on negative emissions in the future is never optimal because abatement happens too late to avoid near-term damages). Turning to cost-effectiveness models, the authors find that a constraint on cumulative emissions produces the second-best welfare outcomes, and a temperature constraint that allows temperature to overshoot the 1.5°C target before 2100 is third-best. By contrast, a constraint on CO2 concentration (with overshoot allowed) results in insufficient early abatement, leading to a substantial welfare loss of US$29 trillion, spread out over the century. Repeating these analyses with a 2°C target, all cost-effectiveness models lead to emissions abatement that happens too late to be optimal, but the welfare impact of this inefficiency is milder. Again, a CO2 concentration constraint with target overshoot produces the worst results, compared with the welfare-maximising cost-benefit benchmark."
"When using climate models to calculate optimal greenhouse gas emission scenarios, there are two common approaches: cost-benefit analysis and cost-effectiveness analysis. Cost-benefit analysis minimises the cost of emission reductions and the anticipated costs of damage caused by climate change over the coming centuries; at the same time, the model maximises human welfare. Cost-effectiveness analysis minimises only the cost of emission ...
More